What stock market returns to expect for the future?

被引:0
|
作者
Diamond, PA [1 ]
机构
[1] MIT, Cambridge, MA 02139 USA
关键词
D O I
暂无
中图分类号
C93 [管理学]; D035 [国家行政管理]; D523 [行政管理]; D63 [国家行政管理];
学科分类号
12 ; 1201 ; 1202 ; 120202 ; 1204 ; 120401 ;
摘要
In evaluating proposals for reforming Social Security that involve stock investments, the Office of the Chief Actuary (OCACT) has generally used a 7.0 percent real return for stocks. The 1994-96 Advisory Council specified that OCACT should use that return in making its 75-year projections of investment-based reform proposals. The assumed ultimate real return on Treasury bonds of 3.0 percent implies a long-run equity premium of 4.0 percent. There are two equity-premium concepts: the realized equity premium, which is measured by the actual rates of return; and the required equity premium, which investors expect to receive for being willing to hold available stocks and bonds. Over the past two centuries, the realized premium was 3.5 percent on average, but 5.2 percent for 1926 to 1998. Some critics argue that the 7.0 percent projected stock returns are too high. They base their arguments on recent developments in the capital market, the current high value of the stock market, and the expectation of slower economic growth. Increased use of mutual funds and the decline in their costs suggest a lower required premium, as does the rising fraction of the American public investing in stocks. The size of the decrease is limited, however, because the largest cost savings do not apply to the very wealthy and to large institutional investors, who hold a much larger share of the stock market's total value than do new investors. These trends suggest a lower equity premium for projections than the 5.2 percent of the past 75 years. Also, a declining required premium is likely to imply a temporary increase in the realized premium because a rising willingness to hold stocks tends to increase their price. Therefore, it would be a mistake during a transition period to extrapolate what may be a temporarily high realized return. In the standard (Solow) economic growth model, an assumption of slower long-run growth lowers the marginal product of capital if the savings rate is constant. But lower savings as growth slows should partially or fully offset that effect. The present high stock prices, together with projected slow economic growth, are not consistent with a 7.0 percent return. With a plausible level of adjusted dividends (dividends plus net share repurchases), the ratio of stock value to gross domestic product (GDP) would rise more than 20-fold over 75 years. Similarly, the steady-state Gordon formula-that stock returns equal the adjusted dividend yield plus the growth rate of stock prices (equal to that of GDP)suggests a return of roughly 4.0 percent to 4.5 percent. Moreover, when relative stock values have been high, returns over the following decade have tended to be low. To eliminate the inconsistency posed by the assumed 7.0 percent return, one could assume higher GDP growth, a lower long-run stock return, or a lower short-run stock return with a 7.0 percent return on a lower base thereafter. For example, with an adjusted dividend yield of 2.5 percent to 3.0 percent, the market would have to decline about 35 percent to 45 percent in real terms over the next decade to reach steady state. In short, either the stock market is overvalued and requires a correction to justify a 7.0 percent return thereafter, or it is correctly valued and the long-run return is substantially lower than 7.0 percent (or some combination). This article argues that the "overvalued" view is more convincing, since the "correctly valued" hypothesis implies an implausibly small equity premium. Although OCACT could adopt a lower rate for the entire 75-year period, a better approach would be to assume lower returns over the next decade and a 7.0 percent return thereafter.
引用
收藏
页码:38 / 52
页数:15
相关论文
共 50 条
  • [41] Stock Market Returns and GDP News
    Patatoukas, Panos N.
    JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING AUDITING AND FINANCE, 2021, 36 (04): : 776 - 801
  • [42] The reaction of stock market returns to unemployment
    Gonzalo, Jesus
    Taamouti, Abderrahim
    STUDIES IN NONLINEAR DYNAMICS AND ECONOMETRICS, 2017, 21 (04):
  • [43] A wave function for stock market returns
    Ataullah, Ali
    Davidson, Ian
    Tippett, Mark
    PHYSICA A-STATISTICAL MECHANICS AND ITS APPLICATIONS, 2009, 388 (04) : 455 - 461
  • [44] PREDICTING STOCK RETURNS IN AN EFFICIENT MARKET
    BALVERS, RJ
    COSIMANO, TF
    MCDONALD, B
    JOURNAL OF FINANCE, 1990, 45 (04): : 1109 - 1128
  • [45] Noisy information and stock market returns
    Li, Gang
    STUDIES IN ECONOMICS AND FINANCE, 2016, 33 (03) : 338 - 358
  • [46] Average correlation and stock market returns
    Pollet, Joshua M.
    Wilson, Mungo
    JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL ECONOMICS, 2010, 96 (03) : 364 - 380
  • [47] Macroeconomic shocks and stock market returns
    Baek, Seungho
    Glambosky, Mina
    Mohanty, Sunil
    APPLIED ECONOMICS LETTERS, 2024,
  • [48] Overconfidence and US stock market returns
    Apergis, Nicholas
    FINANCE RESEARCH LETTERS, 2022, 45
  • [49] Predictability of returns in the Chilean stock market
    Walker, E
    TRIMESTRE ECONOMICO, 2000, 67 (267): : 355 - 394
  • [50] Overnight returns, daytime reversals, and future stock returns
    Akbas, Ferhat
    Boehmer, Ekkehart
    Jiang, Chao
    Koch, Paul D.
    JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL ECONOMICS, 2022, 145 (03) : 850 - 875