What stock market returns to expect for the future?

被引:0
|
作者
Diamond, PA [1 ]
机构
[1] MIT, Cambridge, MA 02139 USA
关键词
D O I
暂无
中图分类号
C93 [管理学]; D035 [国家行政管理]; D523 [行政管理]; D63 [国家行政管理];
学科分类号
12 ; 1201 ; 1202 ; 120202 ; 1204 ; 120401 ;
摘要
In evaluating proposals for reforming Social Security that involve stock investments, the Office of the Chief Actuary (OCACT) has generally used a 7.0 percent real return for stocks. The 1994-96 Advisory Council specified that OCACT should use that return in making its 75-year projections of investment-based reform proposals. The assumed ultimate real return on Treasury bonds of 3.0 percent implies a long-run equity premium of 4.0 percent. There are two equity-premium concepts: the realized equity premium, which is measured by the actual rates of return; and the required equity premium, which investors expect to receive for being willing to hold available stocks and bonds. Over the past two centuries, the realized premium was 3.5 percent on average, but 5.2 percent for 1926 to 1998. Some critics argue that the 7.0 percent projected stock returns are too high. They base their arguments on recent developments in the capital market, the current high value of the stock market, and the expectation of slower economic growth. Increased use of mutual funds and the decline in their costs suggest a lower required premium, as does the rising fraction of the American public investing in stocks. The size of the decrease is limited, however, because the largest cost savings do not apply to the very wealthy and to large institutional investors, who hold a much larger share of the stock market's total value than do new investors. These trends suggest a lower equity premium for projections than the 5.2 percent of the past 75 years. Also, a declining required premium is likely to imply a temporary increase in the realized premium because a rising willingness to hold stocks tends to increase their price. Therefore, it would be a mistake during a transition period to extrapolate what may be a temporarily high realized return. In the standard (Solow) economic growth model, an assumption of slower long-run growth lowers the marginal product of capital if the savings rate is constant. But lower savings as growth slows should partially or fully offset that effect. The present high stock prices, together with projected slow economic growth, are not consistent with a 7.0 percent return. With a plausible level of adjusted dividends (dividends plus net share repurchases), the ratio of stock value to gross domestic product (GDP) would rise more than 20-fold over 75 years. Similarly, the steady-state Gordon formula-that stock returns equal the adjusted dividend yield plus the growth rate of stock prices (equal to that of GDP)suggests a return of roughly 4.0 percent to 4.5 percent. Moreover, when relative stock values have been high, returns over the following decade have tended to be low. To eliminate the inconsistency posed by the assumed 7.0 percent return, one could assume higher GDP growth, a lower long-run stock return, or a lower short-run stock return with a 7.0 percent return on a lower base thereafter. For example, with an adjusted dividend yield of 2.5 percent to 3.0 percent, the market would have to decline about 35 percent to 45 percent in real terms over the next decade to reach steady state. In short, either the stock market is overvalued and requires a correction to justify a 7.0 percent return thereafter, or it is correctly valued and the long-run return is substantially lower than 7.0 percent (or some combination). This article argues that the "overvalued" view is more convincing, since the "correctly valued" hypothesis implies an implausibly small equity premium. Although OCACT could adopt a lower rate for the entire 75-year period, a better approach would be to assume lower returns over the next decade and a 7.0 percent return thereafter.
引用
收藏
页码:38 / 52
页数:15
相关论文
共 50 条
  • [1] Estimating stock returns - Should investors expect less in the future?
    Jones, CP
    Wilson, JW
    Lundstrum, LL
    [J]. JOURNAL OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT, 2002, 29 (01): : 40 - +
  • [2] Metal Returns, Stock Returns and Stock Market Volatility
    Zevallos, Mauricio
    del Carpio, Carlos
    [J]. REVISTA ECONOMIA, 2015, 38 (75): : 101 - 122
  • [3] Fluctuations in the UK equity market: what drives stock returns?
    Rambaccussing, Dooruj
    Power, David
    [J]. EUROPEAN JOURNAL OF FINANCE, 2018, 24 (06): : 499 - 516
  • [4] What components determine stock market returns in the 1990's?
    Pojarliev, M
    Polasek, W
    [J]. CLASSIFICATION, AUTOMATION, AND NEW MEDIA, 2002, : 367 - 373
  • [5] Market liquidity and stock returns in the Norwegian stock market
    Leirvik, Thomas
    Fiskerstrand, Sondre R.
    Fjellvikas, Anders B.
    [J]. FINANCE RESEARCH LETTERS, 2017, 21 : 272 - 276
  • [6] What makes the stock market jump? An analysis of political risk on stock returns.
    Kim, HY
    Mei, JP
    [J]. JOURNAL OF FINANCE, 1996, 51 (03): : 1053 - 1054
  • [7] WHAT'S IN THE MONEYNESS? MONEYNESS SPREAD AND FUTURE STOCK RETURNS
    Li, Zhan
    [J]. JOURNAL OF INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, 2022, 20 (03): : 70 - 88
  • [8] What to expect in the future?
    Montaner, J.
    [J]. EUROPEAN JOURNAL OF NEUROLOGY, 2018, 25 : 654 - 654
  • [9] WHAT TO EXPECT IN FUTURE
    不详
    [J]. DATA PROCESSING, 1976, 18 (05): : 36 - &
  • [10] ON STOCK-MARKET RETURNS AND RETURNS ON INVESTMENT
    RESTOY, F
    ROCKINGER, GM
    [J]. JOURNAL OF FINANCE, 1994, 49 (02): : 543 - 556