Intangibles and innovation-labor-biased technical change

被引:13
|
作者
Piekkola, Hannu [1 ]
机构
[1] Univ Vaasa, Dept Econ, Vaasa, Finland
关键词
Intangible capital; R&D; Skill-biased technical change; Innovative work; O33; O32; O30; J30; J42; M12; RESEARCH-AND-DEVELOPMENT; FIRM PERFORMANCE; PRODUCTIVITY; KNOWLEDGE; TECHNOLOGY; INVESTMENT; SPILLOVERS; MOBILITY; RETURNS; PATENTS;
D O I
10.1108/JIC-10-2019-0241
中图分类号
F [经济];
学科分类号
02 ;
摘要
Purpose This paper analyzes the productivity effects of structural capital such as research and development (R&D) and organizational capital (OC). Innovation work also produces innovation-labor-biased technical change (IBTC) and knowledge spillovers. Analyses use full register-based dataset of Finnish firms for the period 1994-2014 from Statistics Finland. Design/methodology/approach Intangibles are derived from the labor costs of innovation-type occupations using linked employer-employee data. The approach is consistent with National Accounting and offered as one method in OECD (2010) and applied in statistical offices, e.g. in measuring software. The EU 7th framework Innodrive project 2008-2011 extended this method to cover R&D and OC. Findings Methodology is implementable at firm-level and offers way to link personnel reporting to intangible assets. The OC-IBTC as well as total resources allocated to OC are relevant for productivity growth. The R&D stock is relatively higher but R&D-IBTC is smaller than OC-IBTC. Public policy should, besides technology policy, account for OC and OC-IBTC and related knowledge spillovers in the industries that are most important among the SMEs (low market-share-firms). Research limitations/implications The data are based on remote access to Statistics Finland; the data cannot be disseminated. Originality/value Intangible assets are measured from innovation work that encompasses not only R&D work. IBTC is proxied in production function estimation by relative compensations on IA work. The non-competing nature of IAs is captured by IA knowledge spillovers. The sample sizes are much higher than in earlier studies on horizontal knowledge spillovers (such as for SMEs,) thus bringing additional generality to the results.
引用
收藏
页码:649 / 669
页数:21
相关论文
共 50 条
  • [31] Skill-biased technical change, educational choice, and labor market polarization: the U.S. versus Europe
    Ryosuke Okazawa
    [J]. The Journal of Economic Inequality, 2013, 11 : 321 - 342
  • [32] Directed Technical Change in Labor and Environmental Economics
    Hemous, David
    Olsen, Morten
    [J]. ANNUAL REVIEW OF ECONOMICS, VOL 13, 2021, 2021, 13 : 571 - 597
  • [33] Endogenous sector-biased technical change and perpetual and transient structural change
    Zhang, Pengfei
    [J]. JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS, 2018, 123 (03) : 195 - 223
  • [34] Endogenous sector-biased technical change and perpetual and transient structural change
    Pengfei Zhang
    [J]. Journal of Economics, 2018, 123 : 195 - 223
  • [35] Complex-task biased technological change and the labor market
    Gaines, Colin
    Hoffmann, Florian
    Kambourov, Gueorgui
    [J]. REVIEW OF ECONOMIC DYNAMICS, 2017, 25 : 298 - 319
  • [36] Routine-biased technical change and job polarization in Europe
    Fernandez-Macias, Enrique
    Hurley, John
    [J]. SOCIO-ECONOMIC REVIEW, 2017, 15 (03) : 563 - 585
  • [37] BIASED TECHNICAL CHANGE, INTERMEDIATE GOODS, AND TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY
    Moro, Alessio
    [J]. MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS, 2012, 16 (02) : 184 - 203
  • [38] INNOVATION, TECHNICAL CHANGE AND REGIONAL-DEVELOPMENT
    LAMONT, N
    [J]. REGIONAL STUDIES, 1982, 16 (05) : 389 - 390
  • [39] The fluctuations of China's energy intensity: Biased technical change
    Wang, Ce
    Liao, Hua
    Pan, Su-Yan
    Zhao, Lu-Tao
    Wei, Yi-Ming
    [J]. APPLIED ENERGY, 2014, 135 : 407 - 414
  • [40] Skill-Biased Technical Change and the Cost of Higher Education
    Jones, John Bailey
    Yang, Fang
    [J]. JOURNAL OF LABOR ECONOMICS, 2016, 34 (03) : 621 - 662